Skip navigation
Please use this identifier to cite or link to this item: http://arks.princeton.edu/ark:/88435/dsp01nk322h26c
Full metadata record
DC FieldValueLanguage
dc.contributor.advisorRogerson, Richard-
dc.contributor.authorRubinton, Hannah-
dc.contributor.otherEconomics Department-
dc.date.accessioned2020-07-13T03:32:28Z-
dc.date.available2020-07-13T03:32:28Z-
dc.date.issued2020-
dc.identifier.urihttp://arks.princeton.edu/ark:/88435/dsp01nk322h26c-
dc.description.abstractThis first two essays of this collection investigate the relationship between the firm-size distribution and the city-size wage premium. The third essay investigates the effect of a shock to the steady-state rate of inflation on the wealth distribution. The first chapter, co-authored with Clara Santamaria and Charly Porcher, investigates the role of establishment size composition in explaining the city-size earnings premium. Using administrative data from Spain, we first document a strong positive correlation between city size and establishment size, measured as the number of co-workers. We then decompose the city-size earnings premium into two components: the increase in earnings explained by the increase in establishment size and the within establishment-size premium. The second chapter seeks to explain three key components of the growing regional disparities in the U.S. since 1980, referred to as the Great Divergence by Moretti (2012). Namely, big cities saw a larger increase in the relative wages of skilled workers, a larger increase in the relative supply of skilled workers, and a smaller decline in business dynamism. These trends can be explained by differences across cities in the extent to which firms adopt new skill-biased technologies. In response to the introduction of a new skill-biased, high fixed cost but low marginal cost technology, firms endogenously adopt more in big cities, cities that offer abundant amenities for high-skilled workers and cities that are more productive in using high-skilled labor. The third chapter, co-authored with Ben Pugsley, develops an incomplete markets economy to quantify the distribution of welfare gains and losses of the US “Volcker” disinflation. Even with perfectly flexible prices, welfare costs from a disinflation may be significant for households with nominal liabilities. The burden of wealth redistribution, the benefits of a reduced inflation tax, and exposure to general equilibrium effects on the real interest rate all vary across households. When calibrated to match the micro and macro moments of the early 1980s high inflation environment, almost half of all borrowers (14 percent of all households) would prefer to avoid the redistribution and equilibrium effects of the disinflation.-
dc.language.isoen-
dc.publisherPrinceton, NJ : Princeton University-
dc.relation.isformatofThe Mudd Manuscript Library retains one bound copy of each dissertation. Search for these copies in the library's main catalog: <a href=http://catalog.princeton.edu> catalog.princeton.edu </a>-
dc.subjectFirms-
dc.subjectMacroeconomics-
dc.subjectSpatial-
dc.subjectTechnology-
dc.subject.classificationEconomics-
dc.titleEssays on Spatial and Macroeconomics-
dc.typeAcademic dissertations (Ph.D.)-
Appears in Collections:Economics

Files in This Item:
File Description SizeFormat 
Rubinton_princeton_0181D_13321.pdf2.43 MBAdobe PDFView/Download


Items in Dataspace are protected by copyright, with all rights reserved, unless otherwise indicated.